Please E-mail suggested additions, comments and/or corrections to Kent@MoreLaw.Com.

Help support the publication of case reports on MoreLaw

Date: 06-30-2015

Case Style: Longpath Capital, LLC v. Ramtron International Corporation

Case Number: 8094-VCP

Judge: Parsons

Court: Court of Chancery of the State of Delaware

Plaintiff's Attorney: David Jenkins, Larry Cronin, Esq., SMITH, KATZENSTEIN & JENKINS LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; Attorneys for Petitioner.

Defendant's Attorney: Tom Bayliss, Sara E. Hickie, ABRAMS & BAYLISS LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; Attorneys for Respondent.

Description: In this appraisal action, the petitioner asks the Court to determine the fair value of
its shares in the respondent. On November 10, 2012, a third party acquired the
respondent in a hostile cash merger for $3.10 per share. The deal had an equity value of
approximately $110 million and paid a 71% premium over the respondent‘s unaffected
stock price of $1.81.
The petitioner acquired its shares after the announcement of the merger and
demanded appraisal pursuant to 8 Del. C. § 262. The respondent contends the merger
price less synergies offers the most reliable measure of the fair value of its shares. That
methodology, as applied by the respondent‘s expert, yields a value of $2.76 per share.
The petitioner‘s expert, relying on a combination of a discounted cash flow (―DCF‖)
analysis and a comparable transactions analysis, contends that the fair value is $4.96 per
share.
For the reasons that follow, I conclude that a DCF analysis is not an appropriate
method of determining fair value in this instance. The utility of a DCF ceases when its
inputs are unreliable; and, in this instance, I conclude that the management projections
that provide the key inputs to the petitioner‘s DCF analysis are not reliable. The parties
agree that there are no comparable companies. The petitioner relies, in part, upon a
comparable transactions approach, but I conclude that his two-observation data set does
not provide a reasonable basis to determine fair value. Although the petitioner
thoroughly disputes this point, I conclude that the sales process in this instance was
thorough and that the transaction price less synergies provides the most reliable method
2
of determining the fair value of the petitioner‘s shares. The respondent, however, has not
shown that the synergies in fact amounted to $0.34 per share, as it claims. Instead, I
adopt the petitioner‘s estimate of $0.03 per share in synergies, resulting in a fair value of
$3.07 per share.
I. BACKGROUND
I begin by providing a brief overview of the parties, the respondent and its
business, and the process leading up to the merger.1
I delve more deeply into several of
these and related topics in subsequent Sections.
A. The Parties
Petitioner, LongPath Capital, LLC (―LongPath‖), is an investment vehicle that
began acquiring shares of the respondent in mid-October 2012, about a month after the
announcement of the merger.2
Overall, LongPath timely demanded and perfected its
appraisal rights as to 484,700 shares of common stock in the respondent.3
Respondent, Ramtron International Corporation (―Ramtron‖ or the ―Company‖), is
a fabless semiconductor company that produces F-RAM. A ―fabless‖ semiconductor
company is one that does not manufacture the silicon wafers used in its products, but

1
The factual record is drawn, in part, from the testimony presented at trial.
Citations to such testimony are in the form ―Tr. # (X)‖ with ―X‖ representing the
surname of the speaker, if not clear from the text. Exhibits will be cited as ―JX #‖
and facts drawn from the parties‘ pre-trial Joint Stipulation are cited as ―JS ¶ #.‖
2
Tr. 10 (Davidian).
3
JS ¶ 1.
3
instead, outsources that task to a separate company known as a ―fab‖ or a ―foundry.‖4

RAM stands for random access memory, a ubiquitous component of computers. F-RAM
is ferroelectric RAM.5
The benefits of F-RAM are that it has fast read and write speeds,
can be written to a high number of times, and consumes low power.6
Importantly, FRAM
will retain memory when power is lost.7
Nonparty Cypress Semiconductor Corporation (―Cypress‖) issued a bear hug letter
to Ramtron on June 12, 2012, offering to buy all of its shares for $2.48 per share.
8
After
Ramtron‘s board rejected the offer as inadequate, Cypress initiated a hostile tender offer
on June 21, 2012, at $2.68 per share.9
Ramtron and Cypress eventually reached an
agreement on a transaction price of $3.10 per share and signed a merger agreement on
September 18, 2012.10
Following a subsequent tender offer—apparently in an
unsuccessful effort to acquire 90% or more of the outstanding stock or at least solidify

4
Id. ¶ 4.
5
Tr. 184 (Davenport).
6
JS ¶ 2.
7
Tr. 281 (Rodgers).
8
JS ¶ 11.
9
Id. ¶ 13.
10 Id. ¶ 18.
4
Cypress‘ stock holdings—and a stockholder vote, the long-form merger closed on
November 20, 2012 (the ―Merger‖).
11
B. Ramtron’s Operative Reality
Throughout this litigation, Respondent has portrayed Ramtron as a struggling
company unlikely to be able to continue as a business had the transaction with Cypress
not concluded successfully. Petitioner, by contrast, describes Ramtron as a company
with strong patent and intellectual property protection of its core products, a successful
new management team, and excellent business prospects. Indeed, in relying on the
management projections, Petitioner characterizes Ramtron as a company on the verge of
taking off like a rocket. Perhaps unsurprisingly, I find that Ramtron‘s operative reality at
the time of the Merger was somewhere in between these practically polar opposite
characterizations.
1. Ramtron’s foundry situation
As a fabless semiconductor company, Ramtron‘s relationships with its foundries
were vitally important. Indeed, Ramtron depended on its foundry to manufacture its
products. At the time of the Merger, Ramtron‘s primary foundry was Texas Instruments
(―TI‖).12
Ramtron‘s contract with TI provided that, if TI decided to terminate the
contract, it would have to provide three additional years of products to Ramtron. By

11 Id. ¶ 23.
12 Id. ¶ 5.
5
contrast, in the event of a change-in-control transaction at Ramtron, TI could stop
providing foundry services after only ninety days.13

Semiconductor foundries were the subject of a substantial amount of testimony at
trial. As will be seen, the subject of foundries relates to both the reliability of the
management predictions and the disputed cause of Ramtron‘s poor performance in 2012.
Gery Richards, Ramtron‘s CFO at the time of the Merger,
14 testified that Fujitsu
previously served as the Company‘s primary foundry. In 2009, Fujitsu gave Ramtron a
―last-time buy‖ notice under the relevant contract, indicating that Fujitsu intended to
terminate its foundry relationship with Ramtron in two years.15
The testimony at trial made clear that transitioning foundries is not a simple
process. Semiconductors are complex products. In fact, even the silicon wafers from
which the semiconductors are created are not commodities but instead vary by
company.
16
Additionally, each foundry‘s technology differs and F-RAM, being a
relatively unique product, complicates the process further. Thus, transitioning to a new

13 JX 322, JX 324.
14 Before assuming the CFO position, Richards previously had served as the
Company‘s controller. He appears to have started working at Ramtron in 2004.
Tr. 49. After the Merger, he worked for Cypress for five months until March
2013. Id. at 22-23.
15 Id. at 48-49. Apparently Fujitsu did not definitively terminate the foundry
relationship, but instead, was moving its plant to a new location and Ramtron
determined that the expense of transitioning to the new location outweighed the
benefits.
16 Id. at 291 (Rodgers).
6
foundry requires understanding the foundry‘s manufacturing technology and how it
interacts with the semiconductors as designed, then modifying the product design to
eliminate any resulting errors, then completing several rounds of product testing followed
by further design modifications to eliminate any previously undiscovered errors, and then
allowing the customers to evaluate the product before finally moving to full-scale
production.17
Unlike, for example, consumer RAM that one could purchase at an
electronics store for a PC and then, depending on the model, simply ―plug and play,‖
Ramtron‘s F-RAM often was designed into the product being created by another
manufacturer, thus inhibiting Ramtron‘s ability to unilaterally change its products in any
significant way. According to T.J. Rodgers, the CEO of Cypress, even for a
noncontroversial shift of ―going to a different foundry, to change one of your products,
you‘re looking at two years plus.‖18
In fact, Ramtron‘s own track record of foundry transitions suggests that two years
probably is a significant underestimate. When Fujitsu gave Ramtron a last-time buy
notice in 2009, Ramtron already had been attempting to develop a second foundry
relationship with TI. The effort of transitioning to TI had begun in 2004 and took seven

17 Id. at 291-92 (describing the process of transitioning foundries). The Company‘s
products primarily, if not entirely, were for commercial customers. The F-RAM
often was ―designed into‖ the customer‘s end product.
18 Id. at 292. Rodgers also suggested that Ramtron‘s products had design flaws that
increased the difficulty of transitioning.
7
years to complete.19
That transition was not smooth, resulting in product shortages that
caused Ramtron to place its customers on allocation.20
Despite the difficulty of
transitioning from Fujitsu to TI, Ramtron succeeded, eventually, in obtaining a reliable
new foundry.
To increase its flexibility and reduce its dependence on TI, Ramtron sought to
develop a second foundry relationship with IBM. That effort, however, never succeeded.
Thomas Davenport, Ramtron‘s Vice President of Technology at the time of the Merger,21
described the Company‘s attempt to work with IBM. Davenport headed up a team of six
people that worked from 2009 until spring 2012, attempting to get IBM up and running as
a second Ramtron foundry. They incurred $17 million in direct costs in addition to $16
million in capital equipment purchased by Ramtron and provided to IBM to enable it to
produce F-RAM.22
But, in what Davenport considered a ―huge personal
disappointment,‖23 the integration project failed and Ramtron never achieved a single

19 Tr. 49 (Richards).
20 Id. at 50-52 (Richards); id. at 187-88 (Davenport).
21 Davenport began working for Ramtron in 1986. He started as an equipment
engineer and worked his way up to the Vice President position. He currently is
employed by Cypress as the Vice President of Technical Staff. Tr. 183.
22 Id. at 198-99; JX 128.
23 Tr. 198.
8
milestone. To put the IBM investment in context, in 2011 Ramtron had approximately
$66 million in revenue.24
The witnesses at trial uniformly attested to the difficulty of transitioning
foundries.
25 Ramtron‘s own experience with transitioning to TI and its failed attempt to
develop IBM as a foundry confirm this fact. Nevertheless, on July 20, 2012, about a
month after Cypress launched its hostile bid for Ramtron, Ramtron entered into a
manufacturing agreement with ROHM Co., Ltd. (―ROHM‖), a Japanese company, to act
as Ramtron‘s second fab.26
Ramtron‘s management‘s five-year forecasts incorporate the
purported cost savings that would derive from having ROHM operate as a second, or
even the primary, foundry for Ramtron.
2. Ramtron’s business and finances
Ramtron‘s board of directors installed Eric Balzer as the Company‘s new CEO in
January 2011.27
He hired Pete Zimmer to lead the Company‘s sales department. At
Zimmer‘s recommendation, Scott Emley was hired to lead Ramtron‘s marketing
department. Both Zimmer and Emley had worked at TI and joined Ramtron sometime in

24 JX 215 [hereinafter ―Jarrell Rpt.‖] Ex. 8.
25 Tr. 49-50 (Richards); id. at 198 (Davenport) (noting that the difficulty and risk of
transitioning foundries is ―substantially higher‖ in the case of transferring a
specialty process like F-RAM if the new foundry has no experience with F-RAM);
id. at 291 (Rodgers) (stating that ―in general, switching foundries is a big deal‖
and that the process requires a company to ―in effect, change the product‖).
26 JS ¶ 5.
27 Id. ¶ 6.
9
2011.28
Richards officially became CFO in late 2011 or 2012.29
Thus, as of the time of
the Merger, most of Ramtron‘s executives had been in their positions for less than two
years and, in the case of Emley and Zimmer, about a year.
The difficult transition from Fujitsu to TI caused problems for Ramtron‘s day-today
business throughout 2011 and into 2012. A brief overview of Ramtron‘s sales
process is required in order to understand that effect. Ramtron sold some of its product
directly to customers, but the majority was sold to distributors who in turn sold the
products to the end users.30
Ramtron also recognized revenue on a point-of-purchase
basis instead of a point-of-sale basis. Under the point-of-purchase system, revenue is
recognized when the product is shipped to a distributor. By contrast, under the point-ofsale
method, revenue is only recognized when the product is sold to the end user, whether
directly by the Company or indirectly by the distributor.31
Theoretically, the two systems should arrive at the same results. Unless the
distributors are buying exactly the same amount of inventory as they are selling during
each financial reporting period, however, the systems will result in revenue being
recognized at different times. To take a simplistic example, suppose a company sells
100% of its products through distributors and that the company develops a new product

28 Tr. 63-64 (Richards).
29 Id. at 22.
30 Id. at 158 (Richards).
31 Id. at 30-31 (Richards).
10
in the first quarter. The following chart provides an example of how the company would
recognize revenue under the two different regimes assuming the company sold 100 units
of the product to the distributors at $1 each over the course of a year:
Revenue Recognition Comparison
Revenue Recognized
Quarter
Distributors
Point-of-Purchase Method Point-of-Sale Method
Buy Sell
Q1 20 0 $20 $0
Q2 30 10 $30 $10
Q3 40 20 $40 $20
Q4 10 30 $10 $30
This comparison deliberately highlights an important dispute between the parties in this
case: the point-of-purchase method makes it difficult to forecast actual demand because
the distributors provide a buffer. Indeed, in this example, under the point-of-purchase
method, demand appears to be falling, while under the point-of-sale method, it appears to
be rising.
Several of the witnesses testified that they believed Ramtron‘s point-of-purchase
revenue system made it more difficult accurately to forecast future sales.32
The revenue
recognition system matters for two reasons. First, as already mentioned, distributor

32 Id. at 30 (Richards); id. at 192 (Davenport); id. at 299-302 (Rodgers); id. at 396-97
(Buss).
11
activity can mask actual demand. The difficult transition from Fujitsu to TI forced
Ramtron to place its customers on allocation in or around 2011. Because Ramtron‘s FRAM
already was designed into many of their customers‘ products, those customers
needed to ensure that they would have a sufficient supply of F-RAM. After they were
placed on allocation, many customers apparently increased their orders accordingly.33

For example, a customer that was allocated 80% of its ordered amount potentially would
order five units for every four that it actually needed. This increase in orders led
Ramtron to increase the number of wafers it was ordering from TI. The upshot of this
chain of events was a massive inventory bubble, over-recognition of revenue, and a
resulting cash crunch for Ramtron because it then had to pay for the extra inventory it
ordered.34
Because of its point-of-purchase revenue recognition, Ramtron recognized
these additional distributor orders as revenue, even though the over-ordering was not
reflective of ―real‖ underlying demand, but instead, at least in part, was an effort of the
customers to game the allocation system.
The second reason that Ramtron‘s point-of-purchase revenue recognition system is
relevant is because it allows management to alter the Company‘s revenue by forcing
more inventory into the distribution channels. This practice is known as ―channel
stuffing.‖ As discussed in more detail in Section III.A infra, I find that Ramtron‘s

33 Id. at 50-51 (Richards); id. at 187-88 (Davenport).
34 Id. at 52 (Richards) (describing the resulting difficulty when TI would not extend
credit for the over-order of wafers).
12
management did stuff the channel in the first quarter of 2012, thereby distorting the
company‘s revenue.
The combination of over-orders from customers that were placed on allocation and
Ramtron‘s stuffing of the channel led to a massive build-up of inventory. The chart
below35 shows the amount of inventory Ramtron had accumulated as of the time of the
Merger. Because of its point-of-purchase accounting system, Ramtron already had
recognized this inventory as revenue. As this chart shows, in the first quarter of 2012,
Ramtron had 3.6 times as much inventory as a year earlier.
Ramtron Inventory
6.8 7 5.8 5.4 7
10.7
16.7
22.8
25.5 24.1
21
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
Q1
2010
Q2
2010
Q3
2010
Q4
2010
Q1
2011
Q2
2011
Q3
2011
Q4
2011
Q1
2012
Q2
2012
Q3
2012
Inventory ($ millions)
This inventory needed to be financed, which took a serious toll on Ramtron‘s cash
position. Ramtron‘s primary lender was Silicon Valley Bank (―SVB‖). Throughout 2011

35 The data in this chart is drawn from Exhibit 5 to the Jarrell Report.
13
and 2012, the years affected by the inventory bubble, Ramtron either missed or needed to
renegotiate its loan covenants repeatedly. For example, the Company missed its April
2011 liquidity covenant and received a forbearance for May of that year.36
A July 7,
2011 Form 8-K filing states that on June 30, 2011, Ramtron entered into a Default
Waiver and Fifth Amendment to its loan agreement with SVB, an amendment that cost
the Company $20,000.37
Around this time, Cypress began expressing an interest in Ramtron. On March 8,
2011, Cypress made a non-public written offer to Ramtron for $3.01 a share.38
Ramtron
rejected the offer as inadequate later that month. The offer represented a 37% premium
over the March 8 closing price of Ramtron‘s stock.39
Rodgers described the offer as
including ―a high market premium to say we were serious and not to try to squeeze on
them.‖40

After rebuffing Cypress and renegotiating its bank covenants, Ramtron still
needed capital. SVB apparently had shifted to lending to Ramtron on an asset-backed
basis, meaning that its loans were collateralized by the Company‘s receivables instead of
being unsecured. Ramtron considered borrowing from other lenders, but concluded that

36 JX 22; Tr. 25 (Richards).
37 JX 24.
38 JS ¶ 8.
39 JX 14.
40 Tr. 285.
14
the cost was too high.41
So, in July 2011, Ramtron launched a secondary public offering
of 4,750,000 shares, which was roughly 20% of its outstanding shares.42
The secondary
offering occurred at $2 per share, with a net to Ramtron of $1.79 after underwriting
commissions and other charges.43
The Company used the proceeds of this equity raise
largely for working capital to pay off its excess inventory.44

As the above chart shows, Ramtron‘s inventory continued to increase throughout
2011. Despite the recent equity raise, Ramtron soon fell short on cash again. At least
one internal Company email from January 2012 suggests that the first quarter covenants
would be tight.
45 And, by spring 2012, the Company was in a cash crunch of sorts.
Richards emailed Davenport on March 3, 2012, that ―we are basically running on fumes
in regards to cash management and related bank covenants, which we just announced
new ones yesterday.‖46
These cash management problems continued after Cypress
announced its hostile bid for Ramtron on June 12, 2012. Shortly after the merger
agreement was signed, Richards provided Brad Buss, Cypress‘ then-CFO, with cash

41 Id. at 54-55 (Richards).
42 Id. at 54 (Richards).
43 JS ¶ 9.
44 Tr. 55 (Richards).
45 JX 35.
46 JX 43; Tr. 28 (Richards: explaining that this reference to the new bank covenants
related to the fact that Ramtron recently had renegotiated its covenants yet again).
15
forecasts that showed the Company would go cash negative on October 26, 2012.47
In
response, Cypress promptly began funding Ramtron.
48

Overall, the evidence shows that Ramtron continually had difficulty meeting its
bank covenants, but that SVB seemed willing to renegotiate those covenants. There is no
evidence that SVB ever sought to call its loans or that the Company actually faced a
serious risk of foreclosure. Richards concisely summed up Ramtron‘s relationship with
SVB as ―rocky in regards to the covenants‖ but that he ―had a good relationship with the
bankers.‖49
From the evidence of record, therefore, I conclude that the Company was
cash-strapped and struggling from a liquidity standpoint at the time of the Merger, but
that Ramtron was not, as Cypress suggests, a bankruptcy waiting to happen.
C. The Merger
On June 12, 2012, Ramtron issued a public letter declaring its intent to acquire
Ramtron for $2.48 a share.50
Interestingly, the $2.48 offer reflected the same 37%
premium to market as Cypress‘ March 2011 offer; the decrease in price corresponded to

47 JX 151.
48 Tr. 410 (Buss).
49 Id. at 30.
50 JS ¶ 11.
16
the fall in Ramtron‘s stock price.
51
Ramtron rejected that offer as inadequate in a June 18
press release and announced that it had begun exploring strategic alternatives.52
Only two days after Cypress announced its public bid, Balzer, Ramtron‘s CEO,
ordered the creation of new long-term management projections (the ―Management
Projections‖). While, as discussed infra, the parties vigorously dispute the accuracy of
Ramtron‘s prior forecasts, there seems to be no dispute that the Company‘s management
had not previously created multi-year forecasts and instead generally only created fivequarter
forecasts.53
Balzer oversaw the team in charge of creating the new management
projections, which consisted of Richards, Brian Yates, who worked for Richards,
Zimmer, and Emley.54
A June 14, 2010 email chain among those five individuals shows a team
undertaking a new and unfamiliar project. As if emphasizing that the projections were
not being prepared in the ordinary course of Ramtron‘s business, Balzer wrote that he
wanted a ―product by product build up, with assumptions, for it to hold water in the event

51 Tr. 294 (Rodgers).
52 JS ¶ 12.
53 The sole exception appears to be a set of projections created by Richards in
February 2012 and sent to the Company‘s auditors in an effort to corroborate the
extent of Ramtron‘s net operating loss tax assets. JX 40. Interestingly, the 2013
forecasts included a confidence factor of 80% and the 2014 forecasts had a
confidence factor of only 50%. Richards did not even bother providing a
confidence factor for the 2015 forecasts. Id. (native file).
54 Tr. 59 (Richards).
17
of a subsequent dispute.‖55
Indeed, Richards testified that he understood the purpose of
the projections to be twofold: marketing the company to a white knight and creating
inputs for a DCF analysis.56
The Ramtron management team had never done long-term
projections before.57
Zimmer, the head of sales, wrote that not even the automotive
industry, which he apparently considered more predictable than the semiconductor
industry, ―can do a line item 4 year forecast.‖58
He also suggested that for ―[o]ut years I
would simply plug in 30% CAGR,‖
59 a comment that reinforces the inference that these
projections were not produced in the ordinary course of business based on reliable data.
Additionally, Balzer wanted the projections done using a point-of-sale approach, as
opposed to Ramtron‘s standard point-of-purchase methodology. Ramtron‘s management
team had never done point-of-sale projections.60
I describe the resulting projections in
significantly more detail in Section III.A infra.

55 JX 60.
56 Tr. 59 (―Needham was going to market our company. . . . [O]ne of their tactics
was to put us out to bid so hopefully maybe a white knight would come in. And,
two, I think they used [the projections] for a discounted cash flow to come up with
a basis to value the company, if you will.‖).
57 Id. at 63.
58 JX 60.
59 Id. By recommending use of a 30% CAGR, which generally stands for compound
annual growth rate, Richards understood Zimmer to be advocating multiplying a
base value by 1.3 for each year of the projection period.
60 Tr. 63 (Richards).
18
Meanwhile, Cypress‘ hostile offer continued. On June 21, 2012, Cypress
commenced a hostile tender offer for Ramtron at $2.68 per share.61
Ramtron‘s Board
rejected the $2.68 price as inadequate and not in the best interests of the Company‘s
stockholders. Accordingly, the Board recommended that the stockholders not tender
their shares.62
Shortly thereafter, Ramtron issued its second quarter 2012 earnings, which
were significantly below expectations. In the first quarter of 2012, Ramtron had reported
$15 million in revenue and reaffirmed its public guidance for entire-year 2012 revenue of
―approximately $70 million.‖63
On July 24, 2012, Ramtron reported $14.2 million in
revenue for the second quarter and projected revenue of $14 to $14.5 million for the third
quarter.64
These results and projections placed the Company on track to undershoot its
full-year 2012 estimate by at least $10 million. On July 26, 2012, shortly after Ramtron‘s
announcement, Merriman Capital, the only analyst covering Ramtron, downgraded the
Company from ―buy‖ to ―neutral.‖
65
Merriman also suspended its target price and
observed that ―were Cypress to pull its offer for Ramtron, these shares might very well
return to the $2.00 range or perhaps lower.‖66

61 JS ¶ 13.
62 Id. ¶ 14.
63 JX 47.
64 JX 96.
65 JX 97.
66 Id.
19
The witnesses at trial agreed that Ramtron‘s second quarter performance was
disappointing.67
The parties, however, vigorously dispute the reasons for that. Petitioner
assigns basically all of the blame for the poor second quarter to Cypress and denies that it
resulted from any inherent weakness in Ramtron. According to Petitioner, the
distributors pulled back their orders dramatically in light of Cypress‘ hostile bid, because
they feared being terminated after the merger. For this proposition, LongPath relies
mostly on Balzer‘s deposition testimony.
68
Respondent argues that Ramtron‘s second
quarter results reflected Ramtron‘s own operational failures.
It is conceivable that Cypress‘ offer may have had some negative effect on second
quarter sales, but the weight of the evidence shows that operational shortcomings of
Ramtron were the primary cause of the decline in sales. Ramtron appears to run on a
calendar fiscal year. As such, less than three weeks remained in June (and the second
quarter) when Cypress issued its bear hug letter on June 12 and at most ten days remained
after Cypress initiated its hostile tender offer. The most probable explanation for the
poor second quarter is that Ramtron‘s management had stuffed the Company‘s

67 Tr. 73 (Richards); id. at 302 (Rodgers); id. at 397 (Buss).
68 JX 245 [hereinafter ―Balzer Dep.‖] at 106 (―Part of the reason that sales fell off as
soon as Cypress announced the acquisition is distributors that we had. . . . If these
distributors were not distributors of Cypress product, it was their belief—and I
heard this from Pete [Zimmer]—their belief then that Cypress would probably not
protect them if they consummated the deal and they could be stuck with a whole
bunch of product and, hence, they just stopped buying.‖). There is a potential
hearsay problem with this testimony, but Respondent did not press any such
objection in its briefing.
20
distribution channel with inventory in the first quarter of 2012, and that caused the
Company‘s distributors to order less product in quarter two. I discuss channel stuffing in
Section III.A infra. Here, it suffices to note that, as of the first quarter of 2012, Ramtron
had $25.5 million in inventory, a 264% increase over the previous year. Even assuming
Ramtron‘s optimistic 2012 projection of $70 million in revenue, Ramtron had roughly
nineteen weeks worth of inventory, for which it already had recognized revenue, at the
beginning of the second quarter of 2012.
69
A fiscal quarter contains only thirteen weeks.
Other factors support the conclusion that Cypress‘ hostile bid did not drive
Ramtron‘s poor second quarter performance. First, Davenport disagreed with the
allegation that the distributors were pulling back because of Cypress. Davenport viewed
Zimmer‘s comments to that effect as excuses for not hitting his sales targets.70

Considering that Balzer admittedly based his assertion that the distributors were
withholding orders on out-of-court statements made by Zimmer, who did not testify at
trial, I accord it little weight. Second, it appears from the record that a significant number
of Ramtron‘s products are ―designed into‖ the final products, meaning that the end users
would need the semiconductors to complete their own products and thus would have
relatively stable, long-term demand. This makes it unlikely that demand dipped sharply
at the end of Q2 because of Cypress‘ bid.71 For all of these reasons, I find that, although

69 A $70 million year would equate to weekly sales of, on average, $1.347 million.
70 Tr. 209.
71 Id. at 402-04 (Buss).
21
Cypress‘ bid may have contributed slightly to Ramtron‘s poor performance in the second
quarter of 2012, the main cause of that performance was Ramtron‘s own business reality.
Notwithstanding the poor second quarter, Cypress increased its offer price to
$2.88 per share on August 27, 2012, and extended the term of the tender offer.72
On
September 10, 2012, Ramtron‘s Board again concluded that the offer was inadequate and
recommended that the stockholders not tender their shares.73 During the time Cypress
was pursuing its hostile tender offer, Ramtron actively canvassed the market looking for
other buyers. In fact, Ramtron contacted over twenty potential suitors, a process I discuss
in more detail in Section III.C infra. None of those other companies, however, ever made
a firm offer, even though the most serious of them had access to Ramtron‘s internal
management projections.
Beginning on September 12, 2012, representatives of Cypress and Ramtron
engaged in active negotiations. Cypress increased its offer to $3.01 per share on
September 16 and then again to $3.08 on September 17. Later that same day, Ramtron
and Cypress agreed on the final transaction price of $3.10 per share.74
The parties signed

72 JS ¶ 15.
73 Id. ¶ 16.
74 Id. ¶ 17.
22
the merger agreement on September 18,
75 and the Merger was approved by a stockholder
vote on November 20, 2012.76
D. Procedural History
LongPath filed this appraisal action on December 11, 2012. After the parties
engaged in discovery, the Court presided over a three-day trial from October 7 to 9, 2014.
Eight witnesses testified, including the parties‘ experts. After extensive post-trial
briefing, I heard final argument on March 3, 2015.
I also note, for completeness, that a stockholder class action challenging the
Merger was filed on October 15, 2012. Those plaintiffs moved to preliminarily enjoin
the Merger, but that motion was denied. Thereafter, the defendants in the class action
moved to dismiss. On June 30, 2014, I issued a memorandum opinion granting those
motions and dismissing the stockholder class action with prejudice.77
E. Parties’ Contentions
Both parties base their positions on expert testimony. Petitioner called David
Clarke as its expert; Respondent relied upon Gregg Jarrell. Not surprisingly, the experts
arrived at widely disparate conclusions. Clarke contends that the fair value of Ramtron‘s
stock as of the Merger was $4.96 a share. Jarrell opines that the stock was worth only

75 Id. ¶ 18.
76 Id. ¶ 23.
77 Dent v. Ramtron Int’l Corp., 2014 WL 2931180 (Del. Ch. June 30, 2014).
23
$2.76. Petitioner‘s fair value of $4.96 a share is more than 274% of Ramtron‘s
unaffected stock price of $1.81.
Clarke bases his conclusion of $4.96 per share on a combination of a DCF analysis
and a comparable transactions analysis, which he weighted at 80% and 20%,
respectively. Clarke relied on Ramtron‘s management projections and a three-stage DCF
analysis to arrive at a value of $5.20 per share. He based his comparable transactions
analysis on a dataset consisting of only two transactions and obtained a fair value of
$3.99 per share. Because Clarke found no comparable companies, he did not rely on that
valuation method.
Jarrell rather unusually began his analysis with two premises: (1) that the Merger
price was the result of a fair and competitive auction; and (2) that the management
projections were overly optimistic. Based on these predicates, Jarrell opted to examine
the transaction price and back out any synergies in order to determine fair value. This
approach resulted in a fair value of $2.76 per share. In addition, Jarrell conducted a DCF
analysis, in which he relied upon the management projections he earlier concluded were
overly optimistic. Based on that analysis, Jarrell opined, apparently in the alternative,
that the fair value of the Company‘s shares was $3.08 each, a number coincidentally only
two pennies from the Merger price. As a result of his analysis, Jarrell also concluded that
there were no comparable companies or comparable transactions.
24
Much has been said of litigation-driven valuations, none of it favorable.
78
Here,
the parties have proffered widely disparate valuation numbers which differ, at the
extremes, by $2.44 as compared to an unaffected stock price of $1.81 and a deal price of
$3.10. LongPath asks this Court to adopt its $4.96 figure and conclude that the market
left an amount on the table exceeding Ramtron‘s unaffected market capitalization. This
would be a significant market failure, especially in the context of a well-publicized
hostile bid and a target actively seeking a white knight. But, LongPath itself is a market
participant. It bought its shares after the announcement of the Merger, thereby
effectively purchasing an appraisal lawsuit. Although such arbitrage can be profitable on
the merits when flawed deals undervalue companies, LongPath invested an amount so
small that, even if I accepted its position and concluded that Ramtron‘s true value at the
time of the Merger was somewhere in the range of $4.96 per share, this lawsuit is likely a
less-than-break-even proposition for LongPath after considering its litigation expenses.
Respondent, on the other hand, has submitted an eyebrow-raising DCF that, based on
projections its expert presumed were overly optimistic, still returns a ―fair‖ value two
cents below the Merger price.

78 E.g., In re Dole Food Co., 2014 WL 6906134, at *11 (Del. Ch. Dec. 9, 2014) (―In
appraisal proceedings, the battling experts tend to generate widely divergent
valuations as they strive to bracket the outer limits of plausibility.‖); Finkelstein v.
Liberty Digital, Inc., 2005 WL 1074364, at *13 (Del. Ch. Apr. 25, 2005) (―Men
and women who purport to be applying sound, academically-validated valuation
techniques come to this court and, through the neutral application of their
expertise to the facts, come to widely disparate results, even when applying the
same methodology.‖).
25
II. STANDARD OF REVIEW
In a statutory appraisal action brought pursuant to 8 Del. C. § 262, the Court is
tasked with ―determin[ing] the fair value of the shares exclusive of any element of value
arising from the accomplishment or expectation of the merger or consolidation, together
with interest, if any, to be paid upon the amount determined to be the fair value.‖79
The
Delaware Supreme Court has held that ―fair value‖ is ―the value to a stockholder of the
firm as a going concern, as opposed to the firm‘s value in the context of an acquisition or
other transaction.‖80
―Accordingly, the corporation must be valued as a going concern
based upon the ‗operative reality‘ of the company as of the time of the merger.‖81

Section 262 directs that, in making this determination, ―the Court shall take into account
all relevant factors.‖82
Our case law has made clear that ―[a]ny ‗techniques or methods
which are generally considered acceptable in the financial community and otherwise
admissible in court‘ may be used.‖83

79 8 Del. C. § 262(h).
80 Golden Telecom, Inc. v. Global GT LP, 11 A.3d 214, 218 (Del. 2010).
81 M.G. Bancorporation, Inc. v. Le Beau, 737 A.2d 513, 525 (Del. 1999) (quoting
Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc., 684 A.2d 289, 298 (Del. 1996)).
82 8 Del. C. § 262(h).
83 Gholl v. eMachines, Inc., 2004 WL 2847865, at *5 (Del. Ch. Nov. 24, 2004)
(quoting Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 713 (Del. 1983)).
26
As is well-known, the Delaware appraisal statute places the burden of proof on
both parties.84
―If neither party satisfies its burden, however, the court must then use its
own independent business judgment to determine fair value.‖85
III. ANALYSIS
A survey of the case law reveals that there are four main, or at least recurring,
valuation techniques generally presented in an appraisal action: a discounted cash flow or
DCF analysis, a comparable companies approach, a comparable transactions approach,
and an examination of the merger price itself, less synergies. Like all tools, each has its
own strengths and weaknesses. The parties agree that there are no comparable
companies. Jarrell and Clarke disagree about whether there are comparable transactions,
but the universe of potential comparables, even according to Clarke, is limited to two.
Both sides conducted a DCF analysis, but disagree about certain issues in addition to the
reliability of the Management Projections, such as the proper size premium, the
appropriate method of modeling future capital expenditures, and whether a two-step or
three-step DCF is more appropriate, as well as several more minor issues. The parties
strongly disagree about the appropriate weight, if any, to give the Merger price, which
Respondent weighs at 100%. Petitioner places the most weight on its DCF analysis.

84 M.G. Bancorporation, Inc., 737 A.2d at 520 (―In a statutory appraisal proceeding,
both sides have the burden of proving their respective valuation positions by a
preponderance of the evidence.‖).
85 Gholl, 2004 WL 2847865, at *5.
27
Accordingly, I begin there and then address the utility of a comparable transactions
approach before turning to the transaction price.
A. A Discounted Cash Flow Analysis Is Inappropriate Because the Management
Projections Are Unreliable
A discounted cash flow analysis ―involves projecting operating cash flows for a
determined period, setting a terminal value at the end of the projected period, and then
discounting those values at a set rate to determine the net present value of a company‘s
shares.‖86
―Typically, Delaware courts tend to favor a DCF model over other available
methodologies in an appraisal proceeding. However, that metric has much less utility in
cases where the transaction giving rise to appraisal was an arm‘s-length merger, [or]
where the data inputs used in the model are not reliable . . . .‖87
The foundational inputs
of a DCF are the company‘s cash flows.88
In determining those inputs, this Court has
placed substantial weight on the projections of the incumbent management. Indeed, ―this
Court prefers valuations based on management projections available as of the date of the

86 Doft & Co. v. Travelocity.com Inc., 2004 WL 1152338, at *5 (Del. Ch. May 21,
2004).
87 Highfields Capital, Ltd. v. AXA Fin., Inc., 939 A.2d 34, 52-53 (Del. Ch. 2007).
88 Cf. Laidler v. Hesco Bastion Envt’l, Inc., 2014 WL 1877536, at * 8 (Del. Ch. May
12, 2014) (―Though DCF is more prominently employed in Delaware appraisal
litigation, both parties‘ experts opine that employing a DCF is not feasible here
because [the company‘s] management never made cash flow projections in the
ordinary course of its business.‖).
28
merger and holds a healthy skepticism for post-merger adjustments to management
projections or the creation of new projections entirely.‖89

The reason that ―Delaware law clearly prefers valuations based on
contemporaneously prepared management projections‖ is ―because management
ordinarily has the best first-hand knowledge of a company‘s operations.‖90
These
projections are useful in appraisals, because they ―by definition, are not tainted by postmerger
hindsight and are usually created by an impartial body. . . . When management
projections are made in the ordinary course of business, they are generally deemed
reliable.‖91
By corollary, projections prepared outside of the ordinary course do not
enjoy the same deference. In fact, management projections can be, and have been,
rejected entirely when they lack sufficient indicia of reliability, such as when they were
prepared: (1) outside of the ordinary course of business; (2) by a management team that
never before had created long-term projections; (3) by a management team with a motive
to alter the projections, such as to protect their jobs; and (4) when the possibility of
litigation, including an appraisal action, was likely and probably affected the neutrality of

89 Cede & Co. v. JRC Acq. Corp., 2004 WL 286963, at *2 (Del. Ch. Feb. 10, 2004).
90 Doft & Co., 2004 WL 1152338, at *5.
91 Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc., 2003 WL 23700218, at *7 (Del. Ch. Dec. 31,
2003), revised (July 9, 2004), aff’d in part, rev’d in part, 884 A.2d 26 (Del. 2005).
29
the projections.
92
These factors go to the reliability of the projections. In this case, the
Ramtron management projections suffer from all of these problems.
1. A new Ramtron management team prepared projections not in the ordinary
course using a methodology they never had employed before
The team in charge of creating the new Management Projections consisted of
Richards and one of his employees, Zimmer, and Emley, with oversight by Balzer.93

According to Richards, the projections started with the numbers provided by the sales
department, because most of the Company‘s costs either were fixed or a percentage of

92 Gearreald v. Just Care, Inc., 2012 WL 1569818, at *4 (Del. Ch. Apr. 30, 2012)
(listing these four factors as reasons not to afford deference to the projections); see
also Huff Fund Inv. P’ship v. CKx, Inc., 2013 WL 5878807, at *9-11 (Del. Ch.
Nov. 1, 2013) (rejecting management projections prepared out of the ordinary
course that included substantial speculative elements), holding left unmodified,
2014 WL 2042797 (Del. Ch. May 19, 2014), both aff’d, 2015 WL 631586 (Del.
Feb. 12, 2015) (TABLE); Doft & Co., 2004 WL 1152338, at *5-6 (finding
management projections unreliable because: (1) management themselves did not
regard them as reliable; and (2) the company, and seemingly the industry, was
deemed nearly impossible to forecast in the short term, much less the long-term).
Recent cases continue to evaluate the reliability of management projections on
similar grounds. See, e.g., Merlin P’rs LP v. AutoInfo, Inc., 2015 WL 2069417, at
*8 (Del. Ch. Apr. 30, 2015) (refusing to rely on management projections where:
(1) management never before had prepared similar projections; (2) the projections
were so ―indisputably optimistic‖ that the petitioner‘s own expert testified that a
discount would have been appropriate; and (3) management ―itself had no
confidence in its ability to forecast‖); Owen v. Cannon, 2015 WL 3189204, at *19-
21 (Del. Ch. June 17, 2015) (rejecting an attack on the management projections
when those projections did not include speculative business items, were not
inconsistent with historical performance, were not ―created by novices,‖ and
instead generally resulted from a ―deliberate, iterative process over a period of
three years to create, update and revise multi-year projections for the Company‖).
93 Tr. 59 (Richards).
30
revenue, so the revenue numbers were the most important inputs.94
Zimmer and Emley
were the lead individuals responsible for developing the sales (and, hence, revenue)
numbers. Both had been with the Company at most a year when they began creating the
new projections.95
Aside from having relatively new employees tasked with creating the inputs, the
team that developed the Management Projections utilized: (1) a new product-by-product
build-up method; (2) a point-of-sale instead of the usual point-of-purchase methodology;
and (3) a multi-year projection period.96
The Ramtron management team previously had
not created projections using any of these methods, much less all three.
Additionally, the projections were not prepared in the ordinary course of business.
There is no evidence Ramtron ever had prepared forecasts for more than five quarters,
with the exception of Richards‘s deferred tax asset projections.
97
Balzer ordered the
projections created immediately after Cypress issued its bear hug letter. Thus, these
projections were prepared in anticipation of potential litigation, or, at least, a hostile
takeover bid. Balzer explicitly wrote that he wanted a ―product by product build up, with
assumptions, for it to hold water in the event of a subsequent dispute.‖98
Furthermore, at

94 Id. at 60.
95 Id. at 64.
96 Id. at 63 (Richards); see also JX 60.
97 See supra note 53.
98 JX 60.
31
least Richards understood one of the purposes of the projections was to serve as a
marketing tool in Needham‘s hunt for a white knight.99
This knowledge gave the
management team an incentive to err on the optimistic side.
In sum, Ramtron‘s new management team employed a new methodology to create
long-term projections, which they were not accustomed to doing, out of the ordinary
course of business, with knowledge that the projections could or would be used: (1) in a
subsequent dispute; (2) in marketing the Company; (3) as the inputs for Needham‘s DCF
analysis;100
or (4) any combination of those three possibilities. These projections,
therefore, facially lack the indicia of reliability that generally have led Delaware courts to
defer to management projections. I now turn to more specific problems with the
Management Projections that reinforce the conclusion that the Projections are unreliable.
2. Management’s forecasting capabilities
The parties vigorously dispute Ramtron management‘s forecasting accuracy. One
dispute, for example, involves Respondent‘s contention that Ramtron often missed its
publicly issued guidance for annual revenue going back to 2007, four years before
Zimmer and Emley even joined the Company. This line of attack is something of a red
herring. The proper focus should be on the forecasting accuracy of the management team
that actually made the projections. Whether other, prior executives had or lacked the gift
of seeing into the Company‘s future and predicting the success of its business is less

99 Tr. 59.
100 Id.
32
relevant and barely probative of the forecasting capabilities of the pre-Merger
management team. Accordingly, I would assign little weight to Ramtron‘s alleged
historic forecasting prowess, even assuming it was proven.
The record is surprisingly unclear on exactly what projections were made by the
then-current Ramtron management team, aside from the occasional public guidance.101

The parties‘ main disagreement over management‘s forecasting abilities concerns a
waterfall chart. The chart shows forecasts by quarter. Respondent contends that the chart
represents management‘s ongoing internal forecasts. Petitioner argues that it depicts
nothing but ―stretch goals.‖ The answer is somewhat important. If the waterfall chart in
fact represents actual forecasts, then Ramtron‘s ability to forecast its own business more
than two quarters out was quite poor. On the other hand, if the chart merely reflects
stretch goals, then it loses much of its impact. The weight of the evidence convinces me
that the waterfall chart represented actual forecasts, but I still accord that chart only
moderate weight in my evaluation of the Management Projections. Before explaining
why, I have included below a portion of the waterfall chart.
102

101 E.g., JX 47 (forecasting, on April 19, 2012, $70 million in total 2012 revenue).
On February 22, 2011, Ramtron forecasted between $65 and $70 million in total
2011 revenue. JX 294. Actual revenues for 2011 were $66.4 million. JX 215
Ex. 3. The 2011 forecast likely was not made by exactly the same management
team and neither the 2011 nor the 2012 forecasts utilized a point-of-sale or a
bottoms-up line-item methodology. Thus, the relevance of the 2011 and 2012
forecasts, as predictors of the accuracy of the Management Projections, is
marginal, at best.
102 JX 39. This chart was included in a presentation to the Ramtron Board and is
dated February 9, 2012. The first two columns indicate the month and the quarter
33
Date Qtr Q1
2011
Q2
2011
Q3
2011
Q4
2011
Q1
2012
Q2
2012
Q3
2012
Q4
2012
Apr.
2010
Q2
2010
$21,000
July
2010
Q3
2010
$21,000 $23,000
Oct.
2010
Q4
2010
$21,000 $23,000 $24,000
Dec.
2010
Q1
2011
$21,000 $22,000 $24,000 $25,000
Jan.
2011
Q1
2011
$10,000
$10,440
$15,000 $20,000 $22,000
Apr.
2011
Q2
2011
$15,000
$16,537
$20,000 $22,000 $20,000
July
2011
Q3
2011
$21,500
$21,736
$22,532 $18,000 $21,500
Oct.
2011
Q4
2011
$22,300
$16,905
$20,000 $22,000 $21,500
Feb.
2012
Q1
2012
$14,000
$15,000
$15,000
$14,200
$18,000 $20,000
Respondent‘s argument is straightforward: the waterfall chart appears in a
presentation to the Board,103 and there is no indication that the numbers are anything
other than ordinary-course forecasts. LongPath relies on a pair of ―Sales Update‖
presentations that refer to the numbers in the waterfall chart as ―stretch goals.‖104


when each particular forecast was made. The remaining columns are the quarters
being forecasted. For unknown reasons, there are two sets of forecasts in the first
quarter of 2011. The bolded number represents the actual results in thousands of
dollars for each quarter. For example, the cell Q2 2010 by Q1 2011 represents
management‘s forecast, as of the second quarter of 2010, for revenue in the first
quarter of 2011. I have added the actual results for Q1 and Q2 2012, which were
not yet known as of February 9, 2012.
103 Indeed, an earlier version of the same chart appeared in an October 18, 2011 board
presentation entitled ―Financial Outlook.‖ JX 31. That chart similarly was
entitled ―Sales Forecast Waterfall Chart,‖ as in JX 39, and it contained no
indication that the figures presented were ―stretch‖ goals.
104 JX 313 (Oct. 18, 2011); JX 314 (Feb. 13-14, 2012).
34
Respondent advances the theory (and urges the Court to infer) that Zimmer, as the Vice
President of Sales, referred to the forecasts as stretch goals because, as the head of sales,
he primarily was responsible for failing to meet revenue targets. At trial, Ramtron‘s Vice
President of Technology, Davenport, similarly suggested that Zimmer blamed Ramtron‘s
poor second quarter on Cypress as an excuse to cover up his own poor performance.105
More practical reasons lead me to the conclusion that the waterfall chart likely
represented management‘s actual forecasts. First, contemporaneous emails suggest that
the management team saw these numbers as goals they should hit. In a late January 2012
email chain, Balzer writes to Zimmer, Richards, and Yates that the Company ―really
need[s] to find a way to hit $14.5. That is what we said we would do.‖106
The first
quarter 2012 forecast for that quarter was $14 million, as the chart above shows. Second,
the very idea of ―stretch‖ or ―reach‖ goals requires targets that are, as the names imply,
actually within reach.107
Many of these forecasts were wildly incorrect. In December
2010, for example, the Company forecasted $21 million for the first quarter of 2011 (the
very next quarter), a quarter in which actual revenue was $10.4 million, less than half of
the forecast. Relatedly, as the actual quarter drew closer, management generally reduced

105 Tr. 209, 232.
106 JX 36.
107 See Gholl, 2004 WL 2847865, at *9 (rejecting contention that management
projections were unrealistic reach goals and noting: ―If the 2002 budget
represented management‘s wildest dreams come true, it would be illogical and
callous to key the Bonus Plan to even higher targets that were not achievable‖).
35
its forecasts to better approximate the actual revenue. As the quote from Balzer suggests,
the management team treated these numbers as real targets, not lofty stretch goals.108

Third, if these are not actual forecasts, then the record lacks evidence of regularly created
and updated management forecasts, i.e., if the waterfall chart only contains stretch goals,
then management‘s publicly issued guidance would be the only basis for assessing its
forecasting.
I find it most likely that management began with high aspirations for future
quarters and reduced those expectations toward the actual expected results as the quarter
drew nearer. This suggests that management‘s near-term forecasting abilities were
mediocre at best. Even so, the waterfall forecasts and the public guidance forecasts were
done with a different methodology than the Management Projections. Accordingly, I
conclude that management, even under its traditional forecasting system, was of middling
quality when it came to forecasting Ramtron‘s future business. Several witnesses at trial
testified that, in general, the semiconductor business is difficult to forecast.109
Indeed,
after Ramtron issued its weak second quarter 2012 earnings, Merriman Capital issued a
report that suspended its target price for the Company and stated: ―We simply can‘t

108 The February 2012 projections cumulatively estimate $67 million in revenue for
2012. This is the same number used by Richards in a set of projections prepared
to justify the Company‘s deferred tax assets to its auditors. JX 40. Richards‘s use
of the waterfall chart forecast numbers for projections provided to the Company‘s
auditors further supports my finding that these were not ―stretch‖ goals.
109 Tr. 31-32 (Richards); id. at 320-21 (Rodgers: explaining that rigorous competition,
technological change, and macroeconomic factors make the industry difficult to
forecast); id. at 378-80 (Buss).
36
figure out how to model this company consistently at the current time.‖110 Ramtron‘s
management also recognized its own limited success in forecasting.111
In sum,
management‘s lack of success in accurately projecting future revenue in the past provides
another reason to doubt the reliability of the Management Projections.
3. The projections incorporate unrealistic assumptions regarding ROHM
I also note that the Management Projections assume cost reductions, over time,
associated with the transition to ROHM‘s foundry. The projections reflect an assumption
that production of F-RAM at ROHM would to begin in January 2013 at 150,000 units a

110 JX 97.
111 Balzer candidly conceded the Company was mediocre at forecasting:
Q: What was the quality of those forward-looking
projections when you took over as CEO?
A: Probably mediocre.
Q: Did you attempt to make improvements in the quality
of the projections?
A: Yes.
Q: Did you succeed?
A: I‘d say no.
Q: Why not?
A: . . . [Y]ou need to understand the market . . . . And
while we were working very hard on that, we weren‘t
there.
Balzer Dep. 50. These comments temper the reliability of Balzer‘s position that
the Management Projections ―were the most likely of what would happen if
Cypress walked away.‖ Id. at 83.
37
month and increase by 50,000 units per month thereafter.
112
These assumptions are too
speculative to merit any deference.113

Ramtron entered into a manufacturing agreement with ROHM in late July 2012
pursuant to which ROHM would serve as a second foundry for Ramtron.114
According to
a July 23, 2012 press release, ―Initial low-density F-RAM products have already been
qualified for commercial production and Ramtron expects to receive and begin selling the
first devices produced on ROHM‘s manufacturing line within approximately 60 days.‖115

As already described, it took Ramtron seven years to transition entirely from Fujitsu to
TI. That process went so poorly that it forced Ramtron to place its customers on
allocation in 2011. Ramtron‘s earlier efforts to develop IBM as a second foundry took
place over three years and caused it to incur more than $30 million in direct costs and
equipment expenses. That endeavor failed entirely. Additionally, the evidence shows
that, in July 2012, Ramtron was not flush with cash. The IBM venture suggests that
establishing a new foundry requires a substantial monetary investment, and Ramtron‘s
liquidity situation in the summer of 2012 makes it doubtful that Ramtron would have

112 JX 170 native file.
113 See Gearreald, 2012 WL 1569818, at *5-6 (concluding that the requirement that a
company be valued as a going concern based on its operative reality at the time of
the merger required the exclusion of ―speculative costs or revenues‖); see also
Huff Fund Inv. P’ship, 2013 WL 5878807, at *11 (finding the inclusion or
exclusion of significant contract revenues so speculative as to render the
management projections unreliable).
114 JX 95.
115 Id.
38
been able to finance the continued development of ROHM as a foundry.
116
In light of
this evidence, as well as the uniform testimony on the difficulty of transitioning
foundries, I do not find credible the proposition that Ramtron reasonably could expect to
begin commercial production at ROHM in sixty days and start enjoying cost savings
within six months.117
Additionally, evidence presented at trial buttresses this conclusion. Consistent
with the other testimony on the lead time for getting a product from concept to fullfledged
commercial sale,118 Davenport testified the term ―initial low-density F-RAM
products‖ referred to sample quantities that Ramtron was ―going to take over ROHM‘s
design and try to commercialize them as samples. They weren‘t cost-effective but they
would seed the market.‖119
In fact, Ramtron never got further than this initial sample
stage. Davenport further testified that Ramtron ―never got so far as transfer[ing] our
designs to the ROHM foundry‖ before the Merger closed.120
It also appears that ROHM

116 E.g., Tr. 410 (Buss: commenting that, upon acquiring Ramtron, Cypress
discovered that the Company still had unpaid legal bills from the beginning of
2012). Indeed, Ramtron was on pace to go cash negative before the end of
October 2012. JX 151.
117 JX 170 native file (assumption of per part cost reductions).
118 See supra notes 16-18 and accompanying text.
119 Tr. 225.
120 Id. at 205.
39
technologically lagged behind both TI and IBM as a foundry.121
I do not question the
strategic judgment of Ramtron‘s management in seeking to implement the Company‘s
manufacturing agreement with ROHM, but the record as a whole leads me to find that the
ROHM assumptions built into the Management Projections were speculative and further
undermine the reliability of those projections.
4. The Management Projections rely on 2011 and 2012 revenue figures that
were distorted because of customer allocation issues and channel stuffing
As discussed in the next Subsection, the Management Projections for revenue
assume a constant growth rate of 24% for 2014, 2015, and 2016.
122
This is an arbitrary
method of predicting revenue growth if not supported by reasonable assumptions. Such
simple modeling makes the reliability of the base year numbers crucially important—i.e.,
if a set of projections assumes constant growth from a starting number, the inaccuracy of
that foundational input affects the reliability of the entire enterprise. Substantial evidence

121 Id. at 207-08 (Davenport: discussing ROHM‘s wafer yield of 20% to 60%, as
against a ―good‖ yield of 97%, which TI could achieve, all of which bears on
supply costs); id. at 348-51 (Rodgers: testifying that ROHM lagged behind TI
technologically, was not competitive in the marketplace against TI‘s products, and
had a very different technology than TI that would make the foundry transition
difficult, all of which raised questions about the economic viability of
manufacturing microchips there); id. at 395 (Buss: stating that TI and IBM ―are
probably two of the best, well-run, capable fabs in the world,‖ and that
successfully introducing ROHM as a second foundry ―was definitely a long shot‖).
The testimony of Cypress‘ officers and employees is obviously self-serving, but
their remarks on the technological status of ROHM versus TI or IBM is not
contradicted by any other evidence and comports with Ramtron‘s own difficult
history in transferring foundries.
122 JX 170 native file (year-over-year growth rates of -12%, 19%, 24%, 24%, and
24%, for 2012 through 2016, respectively).
40
in the record supports the conclusion that Ramtron‘s revenue in 2011, the last full year
before Cypress‘ offer, is an unreliable figure.
In Section I.B.2 supra, I discussed the massive inventory build-up that Ramtron
experienced beginning in 2011. During no quarter in 2010 did Ramtron have more than
$7 million in inventory. Over the course of 2011, however, Ramtron shipped a huge
amount of inventory into its distribution channels until, in the first quarter of 2012,
Ramtron had $25.5 million in inventory. Even under favorable assumptions for Ramtron,
that amounts to about nineteen weeks of inventory in the channel and it consists of
product for which Ramtron already had recognized revenue.123
In describing Ramtron‘s
background, I found that this inventory build-up resulted at least in part from the supply
shortages the Company faced as a result of its foundry transition. Those shortages forced
the Company to place customers on allocation; the customers responded by over
ordering. Because Ramtron recognized revenue when it shipped to distributors, it is
reasonable to infer that an unknown, but not insignificant amount of Ramtron‘s revenue
in 2011 actually reflected this over-ordering by customers, as opposed to a genuine surge
in demand. In addition, because of the backlog of inventory that existed in the first
quarter of 2012, it is logical that less revenue would be recognized later in 2012 as the
inventory bubble was burned off, unless there was a significant uptick in demand.
Ramtron‘s management, however, expected to hit their reduced forecasts for the
first quarter of 2012. Although I already have discussed the difficulties with the point-of-

123 E.g. Tr. 415 (Buss: describing Ramtron‘s inventory problem).
41
purchase revenue recognition system, there is another pitfall not yet discussed: channel
stuffing. Channel stuffing is the practice of stuffing inventory into the channel in order to
recognize the attendant revenue sooner, notwithstanding the fact that the revenue does
not correspond to underlying increases in demand. Hence, it is a form of revenue
manipulation.
I find that Ramtron‘s management pushed excess inventory into the Company‘s
distribution channels in the first quarter of 2012. In an already referenced email chain
from late January 2012, Balzer remarked that the Company ―really need[ed] to find a way
to hit $14.5‖ million.124
Zimmer responded: ―I‘ll die trying. We‘ll for sure stuff channel.
Next Qtr will suffer.‖125 There is no persuasive evidence that Balzer disagreed.
Although Petitioner fights the channel-stuffing conclusion,
126 the combination of
Zimmer‘s contemporaneous comments and the massive inventory buildup strongly
support the conclusion that Ramtron stuffed the channel in order to make its first quarter
revenue forecast.
All of this matters for two reasons. First, forcing excess inventory into the channel
in early 2012 meant that there would be a corresponding fall off in revenue at some point

124 JX 36.
125 Id.
126 LongPath cites to statements by Balzer regarding other time periods that the
Company should avoid stuffing the channel. JX 10; JX 242.
42
in the future absent a demand spike.127
As Zimmer predicted, the next quarter, Q2 2012,
did suffer. Petitioner‘s efforts to attribute those disappointing results to Cypress‘ hostile
offer, rather than weaknesses in Ramtron‘s own business practices, are unavailing.128

Second, Ramtron‘s revenue figures for 2011 and the first half of 2012 do not accurately
map to actual demand for the Company‘s products. LongPath argues that the
quantification of the point-of-purchase versus point-of-sale issue reveals that, at most,
Ramtron over-recognized 3.7% of its total revenue from 2010 through 2012.129

Assuming Petitioner‘s math is correct, that is an over-recognition, in three years, of $6.6
million for a company that only once in its history had had more than $70 million in
revenue in a single year.
The problem, however, goes beyond just the amount of improperly recognized
revenue. The timing of the revenue also is affected significantly. If 2011 and 2012 are
used as base years in forecasting, but those years include inflated revenue because of

127 The evidence suggests that many or most of Ramtron‘s products were ―designed
into‖ its customers‘ products. This long-term supply nature of Ramtron‘s business
reduces the likelihood of dramatic short-term demand fluctuations.
128 See supra notes 70-72 and accompanying text.
129 Pet‘r‘s Post-Trial Br. 34. My rather simplistic comparison of point-of-purchase
versus point-of-sale revenue recognition supra suggested that the use of one
system over the other affects only the timing of the revenue, not the amount.
There are various reasons why using the point-of-purchase approach also may lead
to over-recognition of revenue. The distributors may return inventory because, for
example, they ordered too much or the products are obsolete. Distributors also
may sell to the end-user for less than the list price, leading to a reduction in the
actual revenue received. See Tr. 299-302 (Rodgers: comparing the two revenue
recognition systems).
43
either over-ordering by customers placed on allocation or channel stuffing, then the
reliability of the projections is affected. Thus, customer allocation issues in 2011 and
channel stuffing in the first quarter of 2012 throw significant doubt on the accuracy of the
underlying revenue figures for those periods. In that regard, I do not consider it
productive (even assuming it is feasible) to attempt to quantify how much in extra
revenue Ramtron recognized in 2011 or 2012 based on these factors.
130
5. The projections defy historical trends
Historical performance does not control a company‘s future performance. It is,
however, a red flag when projections suggest a dramatic turnaround in a company despite
no underlying changes that would justify such an improvement of business. This is the
classic ―hockey stick‖ problem. The Management Projections, prepared days after
Cypress made its bid and with knowledge that Needham would use the Projections to
market the Company, fall into this category. Both revenue growth and gross margins are
shown as undergoing dramatic improvements. The following chart shows Ramtron‘s
historical revenue (for the ten years before the projection period) versus its projected

130 Moreover, because Ramtron‘s management moved to a new revenue-recognition
approach for the Management Projections, it is not clear what steps the Company
took to avoid double counting revenue. As of the end of January 2012, Ramtron
had about $21 million in inventory in its distribution channels. JX 34 (Zimmer
email). That is more than a quarter‘s worth of revenue. But, the Company
apparently did track to some extent the differences between point-of-sale and
point-of-purchase revenues. JX 174.
44
revenue.
131
As the graphs make clear, the projection period suggests a period of
previously unknown prosperity for Ramtron. Not only is the Company‘s historically
volatile growth rate transformed into a consistently high growth rate, but the downward
trend in revenue is replaced by a sharp, unprecedented increase in absolute revenue.132
This sharp uptick in revenue is in contrast to the fact that, at least dating back to 1994, the
Company never has experienced four consecutive years of growth.

131 The historical figures are drawn from Exhibit 8 of Jarrell‘s Report. These figures
are for the years 2002 through 2011 and are in blue. The projected revenues are
drawn from the native excel spreadsheet of JX 170, which is the final iteration of
the Management Projections. The projection period is 2012 through 2016 and
those numbers are displayed in red.
132 By 2012, the Company had experienced two consecutive years of revenue
decreases. In fact, 2012 revenue was forecasted as less than 2008 revenue. 2016
forecasted revenue, by contrast, nearly would exceed Ramtron‘s 2010 and 2011
actual revenues combined.
45
Presented in another perspective, the following chart shows the Company‘s
compound annual growth rate (―CAGR‖) over various periods.133
Only under the
arbitrary 2005-2008 timeframe, which appears to be the Company‘s best-ever growth
period, does historic growth approach projected growth. When comparing the five or ten
years preceding the projections period, it is clear that the Management Projections
forecast incredible growth. Indeed, the five-year projection period implies a CAGR of
22.73%, which is roughly 3.36 times higher than the CAGR for the five years
immediately preceding the projection period (2007-2011) and approximately 2.46 times
greater than the ten-year period (2002-2011) before the management forecasts.
Time Period Years CAGR
2002-2006 5 7.79%
2005-2008 4 22.73%
2007-2011 5 6.77%
2009-2011 3 18.23%
2002-2011 10 9.23%
2012-2016 5 22.73%

133 The inputs are the same as the previous graph. CAGR provides the rate at which
an initial value would need to grow each year in order to achieve a final amount.
It is a measurement that smoothes out swings in growth over time. For CAGR, I
use the formula: CAGR = ((End Value / Start Value)^(1 / Number of Years)) – 1.
Note that, while, for example, 2002-2011 is a period of ten years, the input for the
CAGR formula would be nine, because there are only nine periods of growth
between year-end 2002 and year-end 2011. CAGR can be a misleading
measurement tool, as the selection of years can dramatically affect the implied
annual return. This is why multiple historical CAGR measurements are provided.
46
Petitioner attempts to justify the Management Projections as reasonable by
comparing the projections to a set of internal Cypress projections. In what was called the
President‘s Strategic Plan (the ―PSP‖), Cypress forecasted the potential F-RAM market in
terms of total available market, service available market (which was Cypress‘ term for a
product‘s core market) and predicted share of the market.
134
Petitioner argues that, if
Ramtron simply maintained the market share of the core F-RAM market that it had at the
time of the Merger, then the Management Projections would be accurate. There are
numerous problems with this argument: (1) Ramtron‘s management did not have the PSP
when they were creating the Management Projections, so this thesis is an entirely post
hoc justification for the Projections; (2) for the Management Projections to be accurate,
Ramtron would have had to increase its market share significantly, not just maintain it;
(3) to the extent that Cypress‘ predictions are relevant, the Management Projections
would require Ramtron to capture a substantially larger portion of the market than
Cypress predicted it would; and (4) perhaps most damaging to Petitioner‘s theory,
Cypress predicted that Ramtron, operating as an improved division of Cypress, would
lose market share.
The chart below compares Cypress‘ predictions for Ramtron, as a division of
Cypress, against the Ramtron Management Projections. Dollar values are in millions.

134 JX 199; Tr. 426-32 (Buss: explaining the various portions of JX 199, which is the
PSP).
47
2013 2014 2015 2016
Core Market $187 $218 $254 $288
Ramtron Share of Market, as Cypress Division $41 $55 $61 $67
Cypress F-RAM Market Share (forecast by Cypress) 22% 25% 24% 23%
Ramtron Management Projections $69 $85.6 $106.1 $131.6
Ramtron F-RAM Market Share (Petitioner‘s argument) 37% 39% 42% 46%
Market Share Gap
(Management Projections – Cypress Predictions)
15% 14% 18% 23%
Petitioner‘s argument is unpersuasive. The PSP forecasts Ramtron as a division of
Cypress—i.e., after a possible merger. That alone makes the comparison of market share
unavailing. More importantly, Cypress predicted a moderate, but falling market share for
Ramtron or, at best, that Ramtron would maintain its market share.135
The Management
Projections predict an entirely different trend under which Ramtron‘s market share would
increase by nearly 25%, i.e., Ramtron would capture another nine percent of the core FRAM
market. By the year 2016, for the Management Projections to be accurate,
Ramtron would need to hold twice as much of the core market as Cypress predicted it
would. Considering all the evidence of record regarding projections, I find it unlikely
that Cypress substantially would underestimate the potential of the very company it was
about to purchase. Thus, Petitioner‘s attempts to show the ―reasonableness‖ of the
Management Projections by comparing them to the Cypress PSP are unconvincing.
Rather, the Projections defy historical trends.

135 In 2017, for example, Cypress predicted a 22% market share.
48
6. Management utilized other projections for ordinary business purposes
The fact which I find to be the final nail in the coffin for the Management
Projections is that Ramtron did not rely on them in the ordinary course of its business.
Although Balzer suggested that the Management Projections were used for other
purposes, such as cash management,
136 the significance of those alleged uses is dubious.
Richards, the CFO, credibly testified that he used other sets of projections for managing
the Company‘s finances, such as providing estimated revenue and cash flow numbers to
SVB, the Company‘s bank.
The final version of the Management Projections utilized by Needham in
preparing its fairness opinion is from September 18, 2012.137
The Needham presentation
listed $58.2 million for estimated 2012 revenue, a slight discrepancy from the native
excel spreadsheet of the Projections, dated August 28, 2012, which listed $58 million for
2012.138
On July 17, 2012, however, Richards sent an email to SVB projecting $56.5
million for 2012 (the ―July SVB Projections‖).
139
On September 10, 2012, Richards sent
another update to SVB that reduced that projection to slightly less than $54 million (the
―September SVB Projections‖).140
Both the July and September SVB Projections pre-

136 Balzer Dep. 80-81.
137 JX 170.
138 Id. & native file.
139 JX 93 & native file.
140 JX 136 & native file.
49
date the Needham presentation. The September SVB Projections are nearly 6.9% lower
than the Management Projections. If the revenue growth assumptions from the
Management Projections were applied to the September SVB Projections, the
Management Projections would overstate five-year revenue by $31 million, even
ignoring all of the other problems with the Management Projections I have discussed.
Richards testified that he believed that the September SVB Projections ―were more
accurate‖ and that he provided those projections to SVB because it was the Company‘s
―sole source of borrowing‖ and he wanted to keep the bank ―apprised of the situation.‖141
7. There are insufficient reliable inputs to produce a reliable DCF analysis
In summary, the Management Projections suffer from numerous flaws.
Specifically, they: (1) were prepared by a new management team, (2) in anticipation of
future disputes and of shopping the Company to potential white knights, (3) using a new
methodology, and (4) were for a significantly longer period of time than previous
forecasts. In addition, I note the following problems: (5) management‘s track record at
forecasting was questionable even under their standard method of forecasting; (6) the
final projections incorporate speculative elements relating to ROHM, (7) rely on distorted
base year figures that resulted from customer allocation issues and channel stuffing, and
(8) predict growth out of line with historical trends; and, finally, (9) management itself
was providing other, ―more accurate‖ projections to the Company‘s bank. None of the
indicia that often justify deferring to management projections are present in this case.

141 Tr. 81.
50
Thus, Petitioner has not proven that the Management Projections are reliable, and I
conclude that they are too questionable to form the basis of a reliable DCF valuation.142
―[W]ithout reliable five-year projections, any values generated by a DCF analysis
are meaningless.‖143
Having found that the Management Projections are unreliable and
there are no other viable projections in the record,
144 I therefore conclude that it would be
inappropriate to determine fair value based on a DCF analysis in this instance.
B. The Comparable Transactions Method Does Not Produce a Reliable Value
The parties‘ experts agree that there are no comparable companies to Ramtron.145

Using another approach, Clarke, petitioner‘s expert, opined that there were two

142 My conclusion that the Management Projections are unreliable prevents me from
using those inputs. It is equally dubious to use either set of the SVB Projections,
because they extend only for the 2012 calendar year and one of the main problems
with the Management Projections is that they forecast an unrealistic rate of
growth. Thus, even if the SVB Projections provided a reliable 2012 input, it still
would not be clear what rate of growth to apply for future years. The parties,
perhaps, could have advised on this issue. Instead of arguing that the Management
Projections should be discounted a certain percentage, however, the parties took
the opposite tactic of wholesale adoption or rejection of the Management
Projections. This has forced the Court to choose one of those routes. Adopting
instead some sort of middle ground would require me to engage in impermissible
and unreliable speculation.
143 Huff Fund Inv. P’ship, 2013 WL 5878807, at *9.
144 Cypress prepared its own projections for Ramtron. JX 174. Those projections,
however, predict Ramtron‘s performance as a division of Cypress. Tr. 321-23
(Rodgers). Accordingly, they are not useful as a predictor of Ramtron‘s standalone
operating potential. Furthermore, Cypress predicted substantially more
conservative figures than Ramtron‘s management, even after accounting for
improvements that Cypress anticipated making to Ramtron.
145 JX 214 [hereinafter ―Clarke Rpt.‖] at 47; Jarrell Rpt. 84.
51
comparable transactions from which Ramtron‘s value could be derived.146
This analysis
resulted in an implied value for Ramtron of $3.99 per share, and Clarke accorded it a
20% weight in his ultimate fair value determination.
147
Jarrell concluded that there were
no comparable transactions.
148
For the following reasons, I conclude that Petitioner has
not proven that the comparable transactions method is an appropriate valuation technique
in this case.
A comparable transactions approach requires ―identifying similar transactions,
quantifying those transactions through financial metrics, and then applying the metrics to
the company at issue to ascertain a value. The utility of a comparable transactions
methodology is directly linked to the ‗similarity between the company the court is
valuing and the companies used for comparison.‘‖149
―Reliance on a comparable
companies or comparable transactions approach is improper where the purported
‗comparables‘ involve significantly different products or services than the company
whose appraisal is at issue, or vastly different multiples.‖
150

146 Clarke Rpt. 51.
147 Id. at 58.
148 Jarrell Rpt. 87, 91.
149 Highfields Capital, Ltd. v. AXA Fin., Inc., 939 A.2d 34, 54 (Del. Ch. 2007)
(quoting In re U.S. Cellular Operating Co., 2005 WL 43994, at *17 (Del. Ch. Jan.
6, 2005)).
150 In re Orchard Enters., Inc., 2012 WL 2923305, at *9 (Del. Ch. July 18, 2012).
52
The purportedly comparable transactions are the acquisitions of Actel Corporation
(―Actel‖) and Virage Logic Corporation (―Virage‖), both of which Clarke concluded
were companies that produced memory products but, like Ramtron, operated without
their own foundry.151
Clarke computed multiples for the two firms based on the
transactions involving them for the following financial metrics: (1) equity value
(―EV‖)/last twelve months‘ revenue (―LTM‖); (2) EV/next twelve months‘ forecasted
revenue (―NTM‖); and (3) EV/NTM + 1.152
Clarke then averaged the Virage and Actel
multiples and derived an implied value for Ramtron from them.
Jarrell contests Clarke‘s choice of comparable transactions. He notes that the
proxy statement in the Virage transaction included a list of comparable companies from
two industries similar to Virage‘s and that Ramtron was not listed in either group.153
It is
unclear whether Jarrell believes that Actel is not comparable in and of itself, but he did
observe that the multiples for that company support the Merger price as evidence of fair
value. More importantly, Jarrell opines that the dispersion of the multiples for Actel and
Virage is too great to be reliable and violates the ―law of one price.‖
154
I agree with this
criticism.

151 Clarke Rpt. 50-51.
152 This is ―forecasted revenue for the one-year period after the next 12 months.‖ Id.
at 53.
153 JX 216 [hereinafter ―Jarrell Rebuttal Rpt.‖] at 38.
154 Id.
53
In the past, ―[t]his Court has found comparable transactions analyses that used as
few as five transactions and two transactions to be unreliable.‖155
This ―dearth of data
points . . . undermines the reliability‖ of the methodology.156
Here, there are only two
data points and the multiples (shown below) differ significantly.157
Target Company EV/LTM
Revenue
EV/NTM
Revenue
EV/NTM + 1
Revenue
Virage 4.43x 2.80x 2.25x
Actel 2.05x 1.72x 1.65x
Average 3.24x 2.26x 1.95x
Ramtron Financials $58.2M $69.0M $85.6M
Implied158
Equity Value
(Unadjusted
for Synergies)
$181.1M $148.4M $159.7M
Clarke then went on to: (1) subtract a 13% synergy discount from each of the implied
equity values; and (2) average the three figures to arrive at a comparable-transactionsbased
equity value for Ramtron of $141.9 million.

155 Merion Capital, L.P. v. 3M Cogent, Inc., 2013 WL 3793896, at *8 (Del. Ch. July
8, 2013) (citing In re John Q. Hammons Hotels Inc. S’holder Litig., 2011 WL
227634, at *5 (Del. Ch. Jan. 14, 2011) and In re U.S. Cellular Operating Co.,
2005 WL 43994, at *18).
156 Id.
157 Clarke Rpt. 54.
158 The implied equity value is not an exact multiple, because Ramtron‘s debt of $8.8
million is subtracted out and the Company‘s cash of $1.3 million is added into the
calculation. This results in netting out $7.5 million to obtain the implied equity
value that is shown.
54
Even assuming these two transactions qualitatively are comparable transactions, in
that the acquired companies operated similar businesses to Ramtron, the meager number
of data points and the range of multiples indicate that this valuation approach is of
questionable reliability in this instance. The EV/LTM multiple, for example, yields
synergy-adjusted per share values of $2.74 to $6.13, a range of $3.39, which exceeds the
Merger price of $3.10.
159
The EV/NTM multiple suggests equity values of $2.72 to
$4.55, a spread of $1.83.160
By contrast, the EV/NTM+1 multiple produces a tighter
range of $3.27 to $4.53.
I see little justification for Clarke‘s simple averaging method, particularly with
only two data points. His comparable transactions approach implies per share values
ranging anywhere from $2.72 to $6.13. Two of the multiples have high-low ranges
exceeding Ramtron‘s unaffected stock price. I am not convinced it is productive to
utilize a method that implies Ramtron‘s fair value is somewhere between 88% and 198%
of the deal price.161
Also, the EV/NTM and EV/NTM+1 multiples rely on the

159 This calculation is derived by applying the comparable transaction multiples to
Ramtron‘s financials, subtracting $7.5 million, discounting by 13%, and then
dividing by the number of shares, which I assume to be Clarke‘s figure of
35,528,425. Jarrell contends that the latter figure understates the number of shares
by about four million units because of restricted stock and stock options.
160 These numbers are inconsequentially different from Jarrell‘s calculations. The
deviation seemingly results from his rounding of Clarke‘s determination of shares
outstanding to 35,500,000.
161 Jarrell presents a colorable argument that Virage is not, in fact, a comparable
transaction. If correct, that provides yet another reason that the comparable
transaction methodology is not reliable here, but I need not decide that issue. If
55
Management Projections, which I already have concluded are unreliable. Finally, Clarke
himself attributed minimal weight to this approach—only one-fifth of his conclusion.
For all of these reasons, I conclude that Petitioner has not satisfied its burden of proving
that the comparable transactions approach provides a reliable indication of Ramtron‘s fair
value.
C. The Transaction Price Provides the Best Evidence of Fair Value
A DCF analysis attempts to value a company by looking within the company,
extrapolating its financials into the future, and then discounting these cash flows to
present value. A comparables approach instead looks outside the company and attempts
to value it by market analogy. The former method is only useful to the extent its inputs
are reliable; the latter is helpful only to the extent actual comparables exist. Neither
approach yields a reliable measure of fair value in this case. Instead, I conclude that the
Merger price offers the best indication of fair value.
A merger price does not necessarily represent the fair value of a company, as the
term ―fair value‖ is interpreted under 8 Del. C. § 262. For example, in a short-form
merger under Section 253, the merger price is set unilaterally by the controlling
stockholder; the minority stockholders are forced out of the company and left with
appraisal as their sole remedy. To presume that the merger price represented fair value in
such a situation would leave the minority stockholders effectively without the remedy

Virage is not comparable, the Court would be left attempting to value Ramtron on
the highly questionable basis of a single allegedly comparable transaction.
56
offered by Section 262 of an independent analysis of a company‘s fair value. In 2010,
the Delaware Supreme Court in Golden Telecom, Inc. v. Global GT LP162 explicitly
rejected the argument that this Court should ―defer‖ to the merger price. Indeed, the
Supreme Court concluded that such deference would be contrary to the statutory
language of Section 262, which requires consideration of ―all relevant factors‖ in
determining a company‘s fair value.163
Nevertheless, in the situation of a proper transactional process likely to have
resulted in an accurate valuation of an acquired corporation, this Court has looked to the
merger price as evidence of fair value and, on occasion, given that metric one-hundred
percent weight.164
In an oft-quoted passage, then-Vice Chancellor Jacobs wrote: ―The
fact that a transaction price was forged in the crucible of objective market reality (as
distinguished from the unavoidably subjective thought process of a valuation expert) is
viewed as strong evidence that the price is fair.‖165
Similarly, Chief Justice Strine, then
writing as a Vice Chancellor, noted: ―[O]ur case law recognizes that when there is an

162 11 A.3d 214 (Del. 2010).
163 Id. at 217-18.
164 In re Appraisal of Ancestry.com, Inc., 2015 WL 399726 (holding that the merger
price was the most reliable indication of fair value and performing confirmatory
DCF analysis); Huff Fund Inv. P’ship, 2013 WL 5878807 (finding the merger
price to be the best indication of fair value in light of the lack of other reliable
methods); The Union Illinois 1995 Inv. Ltd. P’ship v. Union Fin. Gp., Ltd., 847
A.2d 340 (Del. Ch. Jan. 5, 2004) (concluding that the merger price offered the best
indication of fair value and also performing a confirmatory DCF analysis).
165 Van de Walle v. Unimation, Inc., 1991 WL 29303, at *17 (Del. Ch. Mar. 7, 1991).
57
open opportunity to buy a company, the resulting market price is reliable evidence of fair
value.‖166
The inquiry here is whether the Merger process resulted in a price indicative of
Ramtron‘s fair value or, as the parties have framed it, whether there was a ―competitive
and fair auction‖167 for Ramtron.
At the outset, I note that I am not aware of any case holding that a multi-bidder
auction of a company is a prerequisite to finding that the merger price is a reliable
indicator of fair value. Here, unlike in Union Illinois or Huff Fund, only one company,
Cypress, made a bid. This case also differs in that the Merger was a hostile deal. As
detailed below, however, I conclude that ―the process by which [the Company] was
marketed to potential buyers was thorough, effective, and free from any spectre of selfinterest
or disloyalty,‖
168 and that the resulting price accordingly provides a reliable
indication of Ramtron‘s fair value.
Ramtron could, and repeatedly did, reject Cypress‘ overtures. Simultaneously,
Ramtron actively solicited every buyer it believed could be interested in a transaction.
The Company provided several of those potential buyers with the much-vaunted
Management Projections. No one bid. LongPath contends that the lack of other bidders
indicates a flawed process. I disagree. Any impediments to a higher bid resulted from
Ramtron‘s operative reality, not shortcomings of the Merger process.

166 Union Illinois, 847 A.2d at 357.
167 Id. at 358.
168 Huff Fund Inv. P’ship, 2013 WL 5878807, at *13.
58
1. TI and Ramtron’s operative reality
Much already has been said about Ramtron‘s operative reality as of the Merger.
Petitioner focuses on one particular factor that it contends irredeemably corrupted the
sales process: Ramtron‘s foundry relationship with TI. Under Ramtron‘s manufacturing
agreement with TI, Ramtron was guaranteed three additional years of production if TI
terminated the agreement.169
But, in the event Ramtron experienced a change in control,
TI had the right to terminate the agreement upon ninety days notice.170
LongPath argues
that this change-in-control provision deterred prospective bidders. I reject this contention
as contrary to the evidence.
The parties do not dispute that Cypress began preparing for its hostile bid well in
advance. Part of that diligence involved predicting potential interlopers. Another aspect
of Cypress‘ preparation involved essentially seeking TI‘s blessing for its potential bid.
Because of the change-in-control provisions, Cypress sought to get some form of
assurance from TI in advance of issuing its bear hug letter that TI would not exercise that
right in relation to an acquisition by Cypress. Rodgers testified that he called TI‘s
president to discuss a potential acquisition of Ramtron. In that regard, Cypress offered to
avoid competing with one of TI‘s F-RAM products if TI agreed not to terminate the
foundry relationship with Ramtron. Cypress never received a contract or other written

169 JX 322 (TI Mfg. Agreement); JX 324 (TI Mfg. Agreement Amendment No. 2)
§ 13.1.
170 JX 322 § 14.8(b).
59
agreement from TI—in fact, it appears that TI never explicitly agreed to support Cypress‘
bid. Cypress did receive, however, enough of an informal assurance that it deemed the
risk of proceeding with the acquisition acceptable.171
As Petitioner emphasizes, Rodgers began discussing this issue with TI in March
2011, over a year before Cypress‘ bid for Ramtron.172
Even so, the record is clear that
Cypress never obtained a contractual commitment from TI. In an undated internal
Cypress presentation analyzing the potential bid for Ramtron, the possibility of TI
dishonoring its commitment is listed as a low risk, but Cypress (twice) listed the lack of
TI support as a major risk to any potential deal.173
LongPath argues that Cypress had an unfair tactical advantage and that other
bidders were unlikely to get TI‘s support. This appears to be nothing but speculation.
Ramtron‘s relationship with TI was part of its operative reality. A Cypress planning
document, titled ―Potential Interlopers,‖ listed five such plausible interlopers. For three
of them, Cypress predicted that TI would not extend foundry support because those

171 Tr. 287-90; id. at 289 (Rodgers: ―They explicitly refused to say ‗we will support
you‘ to the point that I didn‘t even try to get them to sign a document, but my
inference was that they wouldn‘t harm us if we didn‘t attack them.‖).
172 JX 320.
173 JX 236 at 7. Because the presentation includes actual numbers for 2011, I infer
that it must be from sometime in 2012.
60
companies directly competed with TI.174
A different document predicted the same as to a
sixth possible interloper.175
I find these predictions and Petitioner‘s reliance upon them somewhat puzzling.
Even though Cypress offered not to encroach on one specific TI product line, ―low power
microcontrollers,‖176 in order to get an informal assurance that the manufacturing
agreement would continue, the uncontradicted evidence shows that TI and Cypress
directly competed in several markets and that the two companies had significant bad
blood between them as a result of two previous intellectual property lawsuits.177
Thus,
applying the reasoning underlying Cypress‘ advisor‘s predictions, TI likely would not
have extended foundry services to Cypress either. But, TI did make at least a nonbinding
commitment to continue foundry services for Cypress.
Petitioner has not shown that any other company that wanted to acquire Ramtron
was in a worse position than Cypress in terms of getting TI‘s assent. Indeed, some may

174 JX 67.
175 JX 65.
176 Tr. 287 (Rodgers).
177 Id. at 286 (Rodgers: ―They‘re a company with many divisions, like us, and they
compete broadly in the market.‖); id. at 287 (―TI and Cypress have a history of
conflict, and they sued us twice about 15 years ago. We won both trials, but
there‘s not good blood.‖); id. at 237 (Kaszubinski: testifying that TI and Cypress
competed); id. at 389-90 (Buss: ―So the challenge for us is that TI does not like
Cypress. TI and T.J. [Rodgers] do not get along. . . . I believe he had been in two
prior lawsuits with them prior to my tenure, and I think he beat them both times.
So there is a lot of animosity between the two companies, and it was the number
one issue we wrestled with.‖).
61
have been better positioned than Cypress. Construed most favorably to LongPath, all
bidders were in the same boat as Cypress vis-à-vis TI. Ramtron‘s manufacturing
agreement with TI simply was part of the Company‘s operative reality at the time of the
Merger.
Furthermore, there is no evidence that the change-in-control provisions in the TI
manufacturing agreement actually deterred any of the potential bidders.178 Ramtron
apparently proceeded the furthest in discussing alternative transactions with three
companies: Atmel Corp., SMART Modular, and ROHM. Nothing suggests that the TI
agreement caused any of those companies to back out. Davenport testified that SMART
Modular was ―very hesitant due to our supply-side cost structure and the tenuousness of
our supply‖ and also did not like the Company‘s ―sole sourcing.‖179
Atmel similarly
declined because of Ramtron‘s ―cost structure [and] in particular our wafer supply,
[which] they were very, very concerned about.‖180
ROHM seems to have been
contemplating a minority investment, discussed in the next Subsection, which would not
have implicated the TI concerns. In short, Petitioner has not demonstrated that the
change-in-control provisions in the manufacturing agreement with TI materially impaired
Ramtron‘s sales process. Instead, Ramtron‘s sole or primary reliance on TI as its foundry
was part of the Company‘s operative reality.

178 Id. at 65 (Richards); id. at 202 (Davenport).
179 Id. at 201.
180 Id.
62
2. Ramtron tries to sell itself to anyone but Cypress
Ramtron authorized Needham, its financial advisor, to market the Company to
other potential acquirers and explore strategic alternatives. According to an August 30,
2012 Needham presentation, Needham had: (1) contacted twenty-four third parties,
including Cypress; (2) sent non-disclosure agreements (―NDAs‖) to twelve of those
entities, again including Cypress; (3) received executed NDAs from six interested parties,
which did not include Cypress; and (4) remained in discussions with two companies other
than Cypress.181
This market canvass reveals that six companies were intrigued enough
to enter into NDAs. It appears that those companies received or at least had access to
Ramtron‘s Management Projections.182
In addition, by August, Ramtron had announced
its new manufacturing agreement with ROHM. Yet, despite this sales effort, not one
company besides Cypress ever made a firm bid for Ramtron.
SMART Modular and Atmel were two of the companies with which talks
proceeded the furthest. As noted, both companies declined to pursue a transaction
because of what they viewed as problems with Ramtron‘s cost structure. The evidence
does not reveal why each and every other company declined to bid for Ramtron. At least

181 JX 125 at 8.
182 The Management Projections were in the Company‘s data room. E.g., JX 84.
Needham‘s call log shows that five companies who had signed NDAs accessed the
data room, though one company that executed an NDA is missing from that log.
JX 88.
63
one that executed an NDA saw no synergies in the transaction.183
A second did not see
the acquisition fitting with the potential bidder‘s strategic priorities.184
Another that
apparently did have familiarity with Ramtron‘s technology was advised by its engineers
not to move forward.185
That company was sent, but did not sign, an NDA.
Not one of the specific explanations in the record relates to TI. Instead, what
evidence there is suggests that these other companies did not see value in Ramtron
exceeding Cypress‘ bid. The importance of this point is amplified by the fact that
Needham‘s call log indicates that the NDAs all were executed in late June,186 when
Cypress‘ bid was only $2.68 a share. According to Petitioner‘s position in this litigation,
at that point in time, the Company was being undervalued by $2.28. Ramtron‘s hostile
bid caused a significant spike in trading volume, as revealed by Needham‘s stock price
analyses.187
Aside from the prospective purchasers that Needham contacted, therefore,
the fact that Ramtron was in play was known in the market. Purely financial purchasers
theoretically could have stepped in and made unsolicited bids and, according to
LongPath‘s position in this litigation, snatched up Ramtron at a fire sale price. None did.

183 JX 114.
184 JX 70.
185 JX 76.
186 JX 88.
187 JX 125.
64
Indeed, no one even bid, including those with inside information, even when Cypress‘
offer was $0.42 below the final Merger price.
Petitioner focuses at length on Ramtron‘s discussions with ROHM. On July 17,
2012, Ramtron‘s management proposed two alternative transactions to ROHM: (1) a
purchase of seven million shares of Ramtron common stock at $3.50 per share together
with a board seat; or (2) seven million shares of Ramtron convertible preferred stock at
$4.00 per share and a board seat.
188
Three days later, on July 20, Ramtron and ROHM
announced their new manufacturing agreement.189
ROHM apparently also was interested
in the potential purchase of Ramtron‘s common stock and, on August 11, 2012,
communicated to the Company that any such purchase would be at $3.00 per share.190

According to Petitioner, ROHM‘s interest in a minority investment at a price
slightly below the deal price indicates that the Merger price undervalued Ramtron. If
ROHM in fact had made such an investment, I might be inclined to agree.
191
But, even in
its email countering at $3.00, ROHM explicitly stated the following:
Actually, one of our concerns at this time is the legal and
financial risk for purchasing stocks of a public company with

188 JX 90.
189 JS ¶ 5.
190 JX 109.
191 Clarke‘s report, for example, suggested that the average acquisition premium in
the semiconductor industry is about 30%, with roughly half of that amount
attributable to a control premium and the remainder attributable to synergies.
Clarke Rpt. 56. An additional 15% on top of $3.00 would imply a minimum
acquisition price of $3.45, exclusive of synergies.
65
a price above the market price. Since we have to justify the
purchasing price to achieve the accountability to our
shareholders, we have to seek profit that can make up for the
paid premium. And we have to be careful to decide the
purchase price in order to avoid impairment loss of assets.192
ROHM itself, it seems, was concerned with justifying the above-market premium.
Perhaps, because of the manufacturing agreement between it and Ramtron, ROHM might
have been able to exploit synergies between the two companies or otherwise unlock value
in Ramtron not available to other bidders. Ultimately, however, ROHM backed away
from pursuing a deal for Ramtron at the end of August. Citing ―growing apprehension in
ROHM‘s own business environment,‖ ROHM determined that it was ―not in a position to
make an investment under present business outlook.‖193

3. Ramtron extracts a substantial premium from Cypress
Finally, LongPath criticizes Cypress‘ hostile approach, arguing that Cypress
pounded Ramtron into submission at a below-market rate. I already have found that, to
the extent Cypress‘ hostile bid negatively altered Ramtron‘s performance, such effects
were dwarfed by Ramtron‘s own business problems, which included channel stuffing
earlier in the year. Those flaws are part of Ramtron‘s operative reality. On the other
hand, there is support in the case law for disregarding temporary distortions in
determining a company‘s fair value.194
In theory, then, it could be acceptable to back out
any negative effects caused by Cypress‘ hostile offer. The parties, however, have offered

192 JX 109.
193 JX 126.
66
no practical way to quantify those effects, particularly as against the larger effects from
Ramtron‘s own business problems.
In that regard, there is no evidence that Cypress‘ hostile approach hampered the
ability of other companies to bid for Ramtron or otherwise affected the Merger process.
Only one company contacted by Needham stated that it did not wish to bid against
Cypress.195
By contrast, six other companies went so far as to execute NDAs. Even if
Cypress was attempting to wear Ramtron down,196 Cypress had every right to do so and
there is no evidence that it acted improperly in this regard. Furthermore, the history of
the Merger runs contrary to LongPath‘s argument. Ramtron‘s Board had the ability to
say no to Cypress and repeatedly did so. The Board advised Ramtron‘s stockholders on
several occasions not to tender into Cypress‘ bid and, over the same time period, Cypress
raised its bid five separate times. The price Cypress ultimately paid—which was
negotiated by the Ramtron Board and Cypress—was 25% higher than Cypress‘ starting
offer.
4. Conclusion
The Merger resulted from Cypress‘ hostile bid. Cypress spent three months
attempting to acquire Ramtron, during which time the Company actively shopped itself to
other conceivable buyers, several of which indicated serious interest. None of those

194 See Glassman v. Unocal Exploration Corp., 777 A.2d 242, 248 (Del. 2001).
195 JX 88.
196 See JX 89 (―Wear them down and wait is working.‖).
67
potential alternative buyers made a firm offer. Cypress, however, repeatedly raised its
price until it and Ramtron‘s Board agreed on final Merger price of $3.10 per share. This
lengthy, publicized process was thorough and gives me confidence that, if Ramtron could
have commanded a higher value, it would have. ―For me (as a law-trained judge) to
second-guess the price that resulted from that process involves an exercise in hubris and,
at best, reasoned guess work.‖197
As such, I conclude that the Merger price is a reliable
indication of Ramtron‘s fair value.
D. Transaction Price Less Synergies
Thus far, I have concluded that the Management Projections are unreliable,
making the use of a DCF inappropriate. Additionally, the parties agree that there are no
comparable companies and I concur with Respondent that the comparable transactions
approach does not provide a reliable indication of fair value here. By contrast, the
Merger process was thorough and supports my reliance on the Merger price as an
indication of Ramtron‘s fair value. In the absence of alternative methodologies, I weigh
the Merger price at 100% in determining the fair value of Petitioner‘s shares.
In an appraisal action, however, it is inappropriate to include merger-specific
value. Accordingly, I must exclude from the $3.10 Merger price any portion of that
amount attributable to Cypress-specific synergies, as opposed to Ramtron‘s value as a

197 Union Illinois, 847 A.2d at 359.
68
going concern.198
Respondent argues that the synergies amount to $0.34 per share.
Petitioner contends that the net synergies are only $0.03.
Preliminarily, I reject LongPath‘s contention that synergies should be subtracted
not from the Merger price, but instead from the value that Cypress attributed to Ramtron,
which, according to Petitioner, is between $3.90 and $5.44. Those valuations estimated
Ramtron‘s worth as a division of Cypress. Petitioner‘s requested approach is contrary to
the language of Section 262, which commands that I ―determine the fair value of the
shares exclusive of any element of value arising from the accomplishment or expectation
of the merger or consolidation.‖199
There is no basis to deduct synergies from the
idiosyncratic value attributed to a company by its purchaser, because it is not clear that
value would provide insight into the fair value of the target company as a going concern.
Instead, the proper way of applying a merger-price-less-synergies approach is to
determine the value paid for a company and then subtract that portion of the purchase
price representing synergies.
200
As to the synergies in this transaction, I find Respondent‘s argument that over
10% of the transaction price represented synergies to be without merit. Jarrell first

198 Huff Fund, 2014 WL 2042797, at *2.
199 8 Del. C. § 262(h) (emphasis added).
200 Cf. Huff Fund, 2014 WL 2042797, at *5 (providing the example of the urban
cornfield auction and the eccentric farmer, and noting that, ―In an auction setting,
it makes little sense to determine whether a bid incorporates information about the
value of certain opportunities by considering only the idiosyncratic weight
attached to that information by any particular bidder, even the winning bidder‖).
69
provided a market-wide analysis of the premia paid by financial versus strategic buyers
and from this approach concluded that average synergies could be removed from the
purchase price by applying the ratio of the average financial buyers‘ premium to the
average strategic buyers‘ premium, i.e., effectively multiplying the Merger price by 0.73,
which results in a fair value of $2.75.201

This general data, however, does not tell me anything about this specific
transaction, which must be the focus in a Section 262 action. With respect to Cypressspecific
synergies, Jarrell compared the Management Projections to a set of Cypress
projections202 and quantified the cost savings, which Jarrell determined to be $0.69 per
share. He then assumed that Ramtron‘s stockholders captured between 25% and 75% of
these synergies and took the midpoint of those calculations, resulting in a fair value of
$2.76.203
In addition to its back-of-the-envelope feel, this approach focuses solely on cost
savings, which are positive synergies, and neglects the possibility of negative synergies,
which Clarke asserts would exist here.
204
Although Clarke rejected the transaction-price-less-synergies approach, he opined
that negative revenue synergies and transaction costs would have to be added back to any
value based on Jarrell‘s estimate of synergies. I find this approach to be reasonable and

201 Jarrell Rpt. 43-44.
202 JX 174.
203 Jarrell Rpt. 46.
204 JX 217 (Clarke Rebuttal Rpt.) at 26-27.
70
supported by the record. The testimony at trial indicates that Cypress expected
significant negative synergies from the Ramtron acquisition.205
While Petitioner‘s
approach may understate the net synergies, I find that it better conforms to the evidence
adduced at trial than Ramtron‘s position. Accordingly, I adopt LongPath‘s approach to
synergies and exclude $0.03 from the Merger price. This results in a fair value
determination of $3.07 per share.
E. Reality Checks
As a final step, I consider it appropriate to touch briefly on some of the ―real
world‖ evidence that Petitioner contends undermines the Merger price as a reliable
indicator of fair value. Some of these items are entitled to zero weight. Balzer, for
example, testified at his deposition that he told Cypress at the time of its nonpublic offer
in 2011 that he believed Ramtron‘s stock would be worth $6 to $8 ―several years out.‖206

This speculation, of course, is not informative as to what Ramtron was worth at the time
of the Merger. Similarly, Ramtron‘s Chairman of the Board testified that he ―personally
would have paid more than $3.10.‖207
The usefulness of a transaction price, however, is
that ―buyers with a profit motive [are] able to assess [company-specific] factors for
themselves and to use those assessments to make bids with actual money behind

205 Tr. 358-61 (Rodgers: testifying about negative synergies in the range of ten to
fifteen percent of revenue); id. at 268-70 (Kaszubinski: same).
206 Balzer Dep. 19.
207 JX 246 at 76.
71
them.‖208
By contrast, hypothetical statements about how much money someone
allegedly would have paid, if they actually had the money to do so, which they apparently
did not, are significantly less probative.
Similarly, I give no weight to the $4 target trading price Merriman Capital
announced in January 2012,209 and reiterated in April 2012.210
By late July, Merriman
Capital had pulled its target price and admitted it could not model Ramtron accurately.211

And, as already discussed, I do not find informative the fact that Cypress‘ internal
documents suggest a value for Ramtron above the deal price; those documents model
Ramtron as a division of Cypress and are not indicative of the fair value of Ramtron as a
stand-alone company.
The one factor that does cause me some pause, however, is the ROHM potential
investment. The fact that ROHM apparently was seriously considering a minority equity
investment at $3.00 per share casts some doubt on the Merger price of $3.10. Ultimately,
however, ROHM did not make this investment and, in fact, expressed serious concern
about paying an above-market price for Ramtron stock. Because ROHM had extensive
information about Ramtron and ultimately decided not to pursue the minority investment,
I discount its importance. ROHM made exactly as many actual bids as the rest of the

208 Union Illinois, 847 A.2d at 359.
209 JX 38.
210 JX 48.
211 JX 97.
72
market: zero. In that regard, the ROHM equity ―investment‖ is simply another nonevent.
Indeed, I suspect that, rather than the Merger price being low, it was more likely
that the ROHM proposal was inexplicably high. Recall, for example, that, in 2011, long
before Cypress made its public offer, Ramtron executed a secondary public offering in
which it diluted its equity holders and sold about 20% of its shares for $2.00 each, with a
net to itself of $1.79. By July 2012, based on the findings in this Memorandum Opinion,
Ramtron‘s financial condition was no better than it was when it made the secondary
public offering. For these reasons, I conclude that the ROHM investment, which never
actually occurred, does not cast doubt on the Merger price as a reliable indicator of fair
value.

Outcome: For the foregoing reasons, I determine the fair value of Ramtron as of the Merger
date to be $3.07 per share. Counsel for Petitioner shall submit, on notice, an appropriate
final order to that effect, including provisions for pre- and post-judgment interest.

Plaintiff's Experts:

Defendant's Experts:

Comments:



Find a Lawyer

Subject:
City:
State:
 

Find a Case

Subject:
County:
State: